By Jeremy Grantham | 24 October 2007
Of course I’m fed up. We had Risk on the ropes. His followers were panicking. They were calling for the ref to stop the fight: "He has absolutely no idea how badly our boy is hurting … he has no idea!" And what does the ref do? Ends the round early, extends the break, and allows a dangerous injection of adrenaline. Risk then leaps out of his corner, apparently rejuvenated, and wins the next couple of rounds. And here we are, wondering whether Risk has taken enough punishment to make him vulnerable to a knockout blow in a later round. Or has he completely recovered?
What a quarter for anyone interested in the workings of the Fed! They had been rather ostentatiously bullied by Congressional visitors over one provisional month’s weak employment data (surely a workable definition of statistical irrelevance), serving to remind us that politics is an occupational hazard for the Fed. But for the record, some Democrat had better get to Senator Dodd (D) soon and explain a basic truth: leaning on the Fed to stimulate the economy in Year 3 [of the Presidential Cycle] is an incumbent party strategy definitely to be avoided by the challengers!
Arthur Burns, for example, was continuously pushed around by Nixon before his 1972 election.1 This is Nixon exhorting him to be more forceful in pushing his colleagues toward interest rate reductions: "You can lead ’em. You always have. Just kick ’em in the [expletive deleted] rump a little." Nixon understood that the independent Fed needed a little forceful guidance from time to time. Greenspan also had his head metaphorically slapped by senators after his vision of "irrational exuberance" in 1996 as the S&P broke past the old 1929 record of 21 times earnings. The slapping was so effective that by 2000, at 35 times earnings, he had become a cheerleader for the new era. But of course we see only the tip of the iceberg through random Nixon tapes and public Senate meetings. The process must be continuous and hard to resist for any but the very strong of backbone.
The result that we can indeed measure is the very long record of the wonderful third year of the Presidential Cycle, when Presidents and administrations really want to be re-elected and really push for stimulus. Employment and GDP improve a little and the much more sensitive stock market a lot. Seventeen out of 19 Year 3s since 1932 have returned over 11% real versus 6.8% for the average year, and only two have been poor (one in 1946 as World War II ended and investors feared another postwar depression like 1919, and the other in 1979 during the oil embargo), a result that is statistically significant at the level of 1 in 10,000. The main cause of this (discussed in this quarter’s Letters to the Investment Committee) is almost certainly more the encouraging tone of the Fed than dramatic monetary action.
This year was heading for the third worst Year 3 in 19 tries, and was only 4.4% real on August 16, with just 6 weeks to go, when the onslaught of liquidity from the ECB and the Fed started. It was still the third worst on September 18 with only 7 business days to go to the end of the presidential year, when the 50 basis points arrived and kicked it up to a 14.1% year. We wuz robbed! Although 14.1% was still far below the remarkable 23.3% average return— a small but welcome mercy.
For a short while I had touching faith that the more "academic" Bernanke would take a tougher line than Greenspan, and he did sound fairly fierce early on, but as the heat turned up he overcame any qualms and threw in the towel quickly enough.
Mervyn King of the Bank of England talked a very much tougher game than Bernanke, positively disdainful of the U.S. and the ECB pandering to the imprudent, overextended financial community: "The provision of such liquidity support," he said on September 18 referring to the ECB and the Fed, "undermines the efficient pricing of Risk … that encourages excessive Risk-taking and sows the seeds of a [far more serious] future financial crisis." My kind of guy! But he too buckled under the combined weight of political and financial pressures and, additionally, he endured the public disgrace of the British enjoying an excuse to have a good old queue [[a real old-fashioned 'run' on the third largest bank in the UK: Northern Rock: normxxx]]. The Brits embarrassingly have always showed such solidarity with the U.S. that since 1932 they have a third year U.S. Presidential Cycle effect in their market almost as large as ours: 22% real versus our 23.3%. It is a telling commentary on who calls the shots in the U.K.: it is not their completely independent central bank, but our completely independent central bank.
And why should we care? Because we agree with the Mervyn King of early September 18 and not with the Mervyn King of late September 18. And because, as we’ve written about before, we are engaged in a dangerous experiment to see how far the elastic band will stretch. The experiment in moral hazard is leading to a series of asset price bubbles, any of which might float out of control. The last bailout produced or at least enabled a housing bubble, and the one before— after LTCM, Russia, and the Asian crisis— produced the real McCoy: the tech bubble of 2000. Each bailout seems to be received with a quicker rally, and negative news is increasingly easily dismissed. The other day it was announced that UBS, Credit Suisse, and the dance champions at Citibank all had to take billions of dollars of write-downs, far more than would have been admissible in polite conversation as little as even 6 weeks earlier. This was celebrated as good news— "it’s all behind us"— so the market rallied 2% for the day, back to its high! What will this new burst of liquid moral hazard bring? Emerging markets would certainly be my preferred choice, and they are indeed shaping up well, having rallied a remarkable 33% since August 15.
So What Happened in the Third Quarter?
There was indeed a genuine severe credit crisis. Either the Fed and others were told some pretty dire things about the state of some major institutions or they are even sillier than I think. The New York Times, The Economist, and others all gave their opinion that some serious financial failures (worse than Northern Rock) must have been feared by the authorities to justify such early and powerful intervention.
|
One can wonder how Countrywide and Northern Rock would have played out with no interference. Big chunks of the credit system had simply frozen. Risk premiums in fixed income widened very substantially in general, with a few exceptions. Liquidity premiums, not surprisingly, widened in particular. But, give or take a few down days, the equity market continued in denial.
Perhaps in the short term they had a brilliant understanding of the lack of strength in the Fed’s knees and in those of their European colleagues. Given the developments in the real world, the equity market’s ability to close up for the quarter is truly remarkable. In the quarter, the housing market was in ragged disarray; corporate profits were okay, but growing far less than in recent years [[clearly topping?: normxxx]]; the dollar was disturbingly weak; and the credit crisis had raged. So equities rally to a new high. Of course that is because it’s a discounting mechanism! Let’s consider what it is discounting: presumed continued dollar problems, almost certain housing weakness, slower economic growth in the U.S. and Europe, weaker estimated profit growth in the U.S., higher commodity prices (particularly agriculture), and more global pressures on inflation.
|
Yes, I get it! Where has the credit crisis left us other than with a carefree stock market? Banks are still not happy lending to other banks, and their rates for this, which surged in the crisis, are still not far from their highs. Mortgages are harder to get and will probably worsen. Leveraged corporate debt is still more costly, harder to get, and contains more careful provisions. On the other hand, credit default swaps, the indices of which doubled in a few days, have backed down 60%. The good news is that very probably the worst part of the crisis— the freezing of all lending— has passed. The bad news is that the reappraising of Risk and other economic effects of the credit crisis will play out slowly over the next year or so.
What Would You Have Done, Smarty Pants?
It’s a difficult question. You couldn’t allow the system to freeze, so even if you wanted to punish the wicked you had to let them off again. And 50 basis points— importantly with a unanimous vote and [prefaced] by massive liquidity injections from European colleagues— probably had enough positive effect on animal spirits to prevent what could have been a financial failure unprecedented since World War II. So the real question is: Why were central bankers forced into a corner where they had to reward reckless Risk taking once again? The bad behavior goes back a long way. (See my 3Q 2002 diatribe on Greenspan, "Feet of Clay".) It is embedded in how the recent Fed has seen its job description. Echoing earlier comments by Greenspan, Bernanke spelled out the problem in September 2004: "For the Fed to interfere with security speculation is neither desirable nor feasible," but "if a sudden correction in asset prices does occur, the Fed’s first responsibility is to protect … to provide ample liquidity until the crisis has passed."
As you can see, they have made no secret about it. To let bubbles form unimpeded and yet to move to cushion the subsequent decline is a simple and workable definition of moral hazard. The fact that they define it as not moving to prop up asset prices, but only to "cushion the economic effects of asset prices declining," is sophistry. It amounts to exactly the same thing. In contrast, The Bank of England, my former semi-heroes, have long maintained that it is appropriate for central bankers to be concerned with asset bubbles, knowing as we surely must by now how destabilizing they can be.
Recognizing bubbles is held to be hard: "To spot a bubble in advance," said Greenspan, "requires a judgment that hundreds of thousands of investors had it all wrong." Greenspan has since contradicted this ridiculous comment many times when describing investor herding and the "irrational behavior" of markets. And his great 2000 bubble, partly indeed his creation, peaked 65% higher than any previous market. Not only did it look like a Himalayan peak, but statistically it was a 3 standard deviation, 100-year event. Far from being hard to spot, it was impossible to miss.
The current housing bubble (Exhibit 1) was also easy to see. The seeing part is easy, but acting is not. It is particularly dangerous to the careers of anyone involved. No Fed Chairman, as Galbraith said, wants to be the one caught holding the pin as the bubble bursts. The pain caused by intervention will be very visible, and the pain avoided by intervention, perhaps much greater, will always be hypothetical. For any normal Fed Chairman (Volcker was clearly abnormal, happily for us), this will always be an easy choice. But if you don’t act to at least moderately restrain major asset bubbles— by all means ignore the medium ones; when in doubt stay out— then you will be backed into ever more corners and be forced to extend moral hazard until its ultimate Minsky moment where no intervention is enough.
Exhibit 1 [see left]
The Current Housing Bubble: U.S. House Prices Will Decline
Housing: Where the Trouble Began
I suggested in 2005 after a trip to Australia ("The Canary in the Coal Mine", 1Q 2005) that the U.S. housing market that was still in bubble territory (Exhibit 1) should turn down in a year because it was lagging the U.K. and Australia, and because it is so reliably mean reverting. For once I got this more or less right, and about a year later we had a first down month in some of the data. Multiples of family income are a simple and powerful controlling factor on housing. Exhibit 1 shows that we in the U.S. in the recent decline (in the Shiller series) have come down about a quarter of the way to usual long-term affordability. Just for the record, how does my beloved Fed stand on this issue? Greenspan in 2005 said there was froth in some real estate markets, but basically it was fine, and also infamously exhorted home buyers to use variable rate mortgages rather than fixed at a time when rates were near their lows, definitely his weirdest piece of advice.
As for Bernanke, in October 2005 he claimed that advancing house prices merely "reflected strong economic fundamentals." Also in 2005 and slightly less cavalierly (but only slightly), he said on CNBC, according to The Economist, "We’ve never had a decline in housing prices on a nationwide basis. What I think is more likely is that house prices will slow, maybe stabilize." Look at Exhibit 1 for a second. The market was deep into a 40-year (2 standard deviation) bubble based simply on a long and relatively reliable price series and its volatility. What was he thinking? Do he and his assistants not look at long-term prices, or has the mean-reverting nature of house prices not yet revealed itself [to them]?
More recently, as yet another example of immoral hazard, his fellow board member Frederic Mishkin argued that since housing prices were likely in his opinion to come down and probably by a lot (20% real), and since he believed the resulting damage to economic growth to be predictable, the Fed should act preemptively— even before any sign of economic trouble. We wonder, when house prices were roaring, why the reverse was not argued and rates raised preemptively to cool housing so that excesses of consumption, extended consumer borrowing, and extended subprime nonsense would not have caused such problems.
Where Are We Now?
Compared with what we might have guessed a quarter ago, today’s outlook for the next year or two may be a little worse: the extent of the subprime problems in dollar terms, how broadly it spreads its pain, how uncertain the holders of the debt were (and are) as to values, and the shocking lack of responsibility in issuing, assembling, and rating this debt were all worse than most of us feared, and many of us feared a lot. GMO’s fear of economic slowdown at least a percent below consensus for 2008 has become more of a mainstream concern. Our general unease with the dollar has now increased and is very broadly shared. And for the first time in 20 years I am slightly worried about inflation.
I have never dwelt on this subject in a quarterly letter, but now long-term intractability with commodity prices may be joined by rapid wage increases in India and China. By the way, like many others I have an increasing distrust in the official inflation numbers. For example, we have rising commodity prices and a very large deficit combined with a very weak currency, yet we have a decreasing inflation rate and one that is lower than that of many European countries with strong currencies. Very odd indeed and a good research project for us.
For the next few months, in contrast to the longer term, the general economic outlook may have improved a little because the unanimity and extent of the authorities’ response to the credit crisis appears to have created some broadly based, if temporary, economic and financial faith that all issues are finely controllable by the Fed and others. This positive jump in animal spirits may actually help the real world as well as the markets, but probably not for more than a few months. (See Letters to the Investment Committee.)
Lurking beyond these current problems lies an interesting new inflationary problem with a very slow-burning fuse: the age profile of the developed world and China. There will be a steady shift in age cohorts with the cohorts of the new workers beginning to decline and those of older workers and retirees increasing. After the Black Death there were more agricultural and urban "plant and equipment," cleared fields to be planted, etc., than there were workers, and it ushered in by far the best 100 years for workers’ pay and income redistribution for hundreds of years on either side. From now on, slowly but surely and with less pain than the Black Death I hope, the generally favorable labor patterns of the post-war period will deteriorate.
Workers will carry more retirees, graduating classes will be smaller (Japan, leading this charge, is already running down well over 10% from its peak), and there will be steady upward pressure on wages, other things being approximately equal, which no doubt will be welcomed by new workers whose hourly pay has languished in the U.S. for decades. GMO will be looking at this situation and trying to assess its implications for markets, particularly housing and equities, over the next several years. Provisionally, it looks quite bad for inflation and for the supply-demand position of both real estate and equities.
Some Near Certainties in Uncertain Times
I wrote 800 words for Fortune magazine a few weeks ago, before the 50 basis points ("Danger: Steep Drop Ahead," 9/5/07. In it I argued that the three things that mattered most to me at the time horizon of 3 to 5 years (the period I’m most interested in) were near certainties and not dependent on whether the credit crisis was stopped in its tracks or was left more or less to run its course. First, U.S. house prices would continue down toward trend over the next 3 years or so, and accordingly mortgage defaults would rise, mortgage re-financings would fall, and all of this would cause a steady drag on consumption, profits, and GDP growth. Second, profit margins would decline globally with negative consequences for stock pricing.
Third, Risk would be repriced on a very broad basis so that some time in the future we would see, once again, a normal or above-normal premium for high quality stocks and bonds. If the crisis were not contained, these effects would occur quickly, and if it were contained they would occur slowly. Now, a few weeks later, I would argue that the workings of the credit crisis— it was more savage than I expected but also countered more aggressively than expected— have left us about in the middle ground: the occurrences of the third quarter have worked to moderately speed up the progress of these three nearly inevitable factors.
My view since March was that a crisis was certainly developing and was more clearly flagged than other important financial events I could remember. However, my "very slow motion train wreck" was not a very accurate description. "Train hits end of track at full speed" would have been more like it, perhaps with the sub-heading, "Several killed and hundreds hurt, but survivors showered with government aid."
Recommendations
No surprises here. For any but the very nimble players of musical chairs and the experts at Keynes’s beauty contest, of which there are clearly quite a few (lucky people), we recommend continued extreme caution. The best hedge against the career risk of being too conservative remains emerging market equity, overpriced but still attractive on a relative basis.
Forecast for the Next 12 Months
To keep it simple, we will use just two variables: the Presidential Cycle and value. Is the market in the expensive half or the cheap half? For the record, the presidential year just ended was an "expensive" Year 3. (As mentioned, since 1932 these have averaged a remarkable 23% real. The actual return was 14.1% real.) We are now in Year 4, famous for its super normalcy including its remarkable lack of outliers, heroes, or villains.
This is an "expensive" Year 4, and the average year since 1932 has been 3% real versus 12% for "cheap" Year 4s. I guess I would happily settle for 3% whilst waiting for the more interestingly bearish opportunities of 2009 and especially 2010. In the meantime I believe global equity markets will struggle to resist going down. Animal spirits have had years of reinforcement from great fundamentals and a friendly Fed, and will not readily abandon ship even though the tide of positive fundamentals has clearly turned and is slowly ebbing: global GDP and the U.S. GDP are both slowing, U.S. profit margins are forecast to decline, and inflation is threatening once more.
A modest up year, with a mixed return to Risk-taking but strong emerging market performance, would be my guess. And in the U.S., a small gain might easily be the result of a higher P/E on moderately lower earnings. Any major bearish behavior is likely to wait for another 12 or 18 months, but accidents do happen, and it should be remembered that the value of the U.S. market based on a normal P/E of normal profit margins is over one-third lower than today’s price.
P.S.: A Perma Contrarian Uncovers an Archive
Most regrettably we contrarians missed out on our real opportunity to be outrageous bulls in the 1930s, but I for one did at least catch all 13 years of continuous underpricing of equities in 1973 to 1986 after the fall of the Nifty Fifty. We at GMO did not get to say much in those early days, but I recently rediscovered the only quote in black and white from GMO’s entire first 10 years, and I must say it would warm the cockles of any contrarian’s heart. The June 28 issue of the Portfolio Letter in 1982, the year in which the market hit 8 times depressed earnings and the lowest price to replacement cost in 50 years, quoted me (deep in the issue) as saying, "…that the market was approaching ‘a major rally, perhaps the biggest in a decade,’ and that our firm’s cash position was ‘nil.’" And just to be mean, since I have the yellowing copy out on my desk, it also quoted Leon Cooperman, the predecessor to Abby Cohen as the Goldman Sachs strategist (of course on the front page), as saying, "…now is not the time to make any major commitments to stocks … for the foreseeable future." Sorry Lee, I’m sure you changed your position by August.
Stop the Presses: A Convenient Recognition
There were also some startlingly heavy scientific reports on how much faster northern ice was melting than the consensus of 2,000 scientists had indicated in the U.N. report. (Can you imagine what it takes to get 2,000 scientists to sign off on anything? The Earth is round, perhaps? So this conclusion that temperature increases were 90% likely to be caused by us actually reflected the 2,000th most conservative view; the median view was almost certainly 99%.)
I normally admire contrary thinking, but it is one thing in a herding marketplace. In science, particularly in our world that really doesn’t like bad news, contrarians can easily produce a smoking-doesn’t-cause-cancer and the-climate-future-can’t-possibly-be-that-bad perspective. But it now looks as if we will have to take climate change seriously. In this case, climate change and energy efficiency will be a giant investment area. And no doubt it will be full of interesting bubbles, of which, perhaps, boondoggle ethanol is the first of this new cycle.
Normxxx
______________
The contents of any third-party letters/reports above do not necessarily reflect the opinions or viewpoint of normxxx. They are provided for informational/educational purposes only.
The content of any message or post by normxxx anywhere on this site is not to be construed as constituting market or investment advice. Such is intended for educational purposes only. Individuals should always consult with their own advisors for specific investment advice.
No comments:
Post a Comment